论文部分内容阅读
I. Introduction
This paper was inspired by the G-20’s request to the IMF to help develop “indicative guidelines”for the reduction of global current account imbalances. Its purpose is to discuss two complex issues. First, why might a country want to reduce its current account deficit or surplus? And second, why might the international community ask for more? Answers to these questions are needed to inform the design of “rules of the game” that countries should abide by, and contribute to the development of corresponding “indicative guidelines.”
Given the focus of this paper, we limit our discussion of the immense literature on imbalances to a few indicative references, without any claim of completeness. For a timeline of global imbalances, an assessment of their prospects, as well as our interpretation of their driving factors, we refer the reader to our earlier work.
This paper is organized as follows. Section II discusses “domestic” reasons why countries may want to reduce current account deficits and surpluses. Section III focuses on multilateral considerations for reducing external imbalances. In the concluding section IV we look at the case for establishing “rules of the game.”
II. Why Might a Country Want To Reduce Its Current Account Deficit or Surplus
This issue is discussed in more detailed in our earlier work (Blanchard and Milesi-Ferretti, 2010), and we therefore cover it here succinctly.
A. Current Account Deficits: Possibly Unwise, and Unsustainable
Deficits can arise for “bad” or “good” reasons. Deficits can arise for bad reasons: examples are financial regulation failures fueling credit booms, and misbehavior of fiscal authorities reducing national saving. If this is the case, correcting these distortions is generally desirable, and will lead to a reduction in the deficit (killing two birds with one stone).
Deficits can also arise for good reasons: temporarily low export prices or bright future economic prospects, leading to low saving; or high marginal product of capital, leading to high investment. But, even in that case, there are still two reasons why one should worry about them. First, the good reasons may interact with distortions, leading, for example, to a dynamic Dutch disease. Or foreign lenders may change their mind, leading to a sudden stop, which will trigger a painful adjustment, more painful than borrowers anticipated or took into account.
B. Current Account Surpluses: Possibly Unwise, but largely Sustainable
Surpluses do not typically suffer from the same stigma as deficits. But they can also arise for “bad” or for “good” reasons.
Surpluses can arise for bad reasons: lack of social insurance, driving up private saving; inefficient financial intermediation, leading to low investment; and other distortions. These distortions will typically be reflected in a more depreciated real exchange rate. With domestic distortions, their removal is generally desirable—again, killing two birds with one stone. Distortions can also arise at the supranational level, for example, in the form of insufficient global liquidity provision, leading to high reserve accumulation, but a discussion of these issues goes beyond the scope of this paper.
Surpluses can arise for good reasons: for example an aging population accumulating saving for retirement, or limited investment opportunities at home. They can also arise from externalities, such as positive productivity externalities from a strong tradable sector, leading to an export-led growth strategy characterized by low domestic demand and high exports (although the net benefits of an export-led growth strategy may decrease over time).
Whether they arise for good or bad reasons, individual surpluses, in contrast to deficits, can be sustained for a long time, if not forever. In particular, protracted current account surpluses do not depend on the willingness of foreign investors to finance domestic consumption and investment, and hence are not hostage to changes in investor sentiment. Of course, they naturally and eventually come to an end, as the accumulation of foreign assets increases domestic wealth, increasing demand and reducing the current account surplus. But this is likely to happen gradually, in contrast to sudden stops for current account deficit countries.
To summarize: we have argued that imbalances can, from the point of view of the country itself, be“good” (come from desirable inter-temporal choices) or “bad” (reflect underlying distortions). When they are bad, a country would clearly be better off eliminating the underlying distortions and thus reducing the imbalance.
But, unless deficits or surpluses have adverse effects, not only for the country itself, but for other countries as well, one may well argue this is ultimately the country’s responsibility. Put starkly, one may argue that every country has the right to be wrong, so long as it does not cause harm to others. To go further, and make a case for multilateral surveillance, one must identify these potentially adverse cross-border effects. To this we now turn.
III. Multilateral Considerations
Three distinct arguments for cross-border effects can be and have indeed been made, one suggesting a case for restrictions on current account deficits, the other two for restrictions on current account surpluses. We discuss them in turn.
Current Account Deficits, Sudden Stops, and Spillover Effects
As discussed earlier, large current account deficits raise the risk of a sudden stop, and experience has shown that these episodes often lead to large financial disruptions. If, as is the case, cross-border resolution processes are poor (and this is likely to remain the case for some time), then other countries will be affected, all the more so given the extent and complexity of cross-border financial linkages. Indeed, the argument is similar to the one for large financial institutions: large current account deficits, particularly in countries that are large and/ or with extensive cross-border financial links, increase systemic risk. Individual countries will typically not take this fully into account, and there is therefore a role for prudential measures.
The argument is surely valid. It was indeed central to the precrisis analysis at the IMF of the risks posed by global imbalances. Specifically, this analysis emphasized the high costs that would be associated with a “disorderly adjustment” of imbalances, featuring a rapid and sharp depreciation of the U.S. dollar, balance sheet effects, protectionist pressures, higher interest rates and risk premiums, and output declines (IMF, 2007). Even if the crisis took a very different form, the worries were perfectly justified.
However, the argument suggests that surveillance, and possibly restrictions, should focus on a broader number of indicators than solely the current account balance. For example, cross-border effects are likely to depend not only on net flows, but also on gross flows. They are likely to depend not only on flows, but on stocks, on the level and composition of foreign assets and liabilities, the distribution of external exposures across sectors, and on the size of the country.
Export-Led Growth, Current Account Surpluses, and Unfair Competition
An export-led growth strategy, that is, a policy combination of a depreciated real exchange rate and enforced low domestic demand(through high saving and/or low investment), is formally equivalent to a combination of tariffs on imports cum subsidies on exports, and low domestic demand to maintain internal balance. This second, equivalent combination is illegal under the World Trade Organization. Should the first one be as well?
One may argue that the first and second combinations potentially differ in their intent. A country that, for whatever reasons (say, poor social insurance, or adverse demographics), has a high saving rate and/or a low investment rate requires a depreciated exchange rate to maintain internal balance. The undervalued exchange rate is then the result of other factors, not of a deliberate policy of undervaluation. In contrast, a country that imposes tariffs and subsidies (and then decreases domestic demand to maintain internal balance) is directly targeting an improvement in competitiveness. But in practice, proving intent or lack thereof may be very difficult.
Can one think of telltale signs? In particular, can the steady accumulation of reserves beyond any reasonable precautionary level be interpreted as intentional undervaluation? Not necessarily, at least in theory. If a country running a large current account surplus has in addition capital controls on purchases of foreign assets by domestic residents, foreign asset accumulation will take the form of accumulation of reserves by the central bank. The simultaneous removal of capital controls and no further reserve accumulation could result in roughly the same exchange rate, with the private sector accumulating significant net foreign assets. In this case, the source of the depreciated exchange rate is not currency manipulation, but the underlying saving/investment balance.
To summarize, there is a reasonable argument for revisiting whether, from a multilateral viewpoint, countries should be allowed to pursue export-led growth strategies; even if such a strategy allows them to catch up more quickly, this happens partially at the expense of other countries. As long as these countries were small in economic terms, the issue could be avoided, but this is no longer the case. The practical is- sue is that, while an export-led growth strategy is likely to show up in a large current account surplus, a current account surplus is no proof of a deliberate export-led growth strategy. Proving intent, namely, that surpluses reflect a deliberate strategy designed to gain competitive advantage is likely to be difficult. Ignoring intent may be politically unacceptable.
C. Current Account Surpluses, the Liquidity Trap, and World Demand
The third argument that has been advanced is that, when part of the world economy is in a liquidity trap, a larger current account surplus in a given country reduces demand and output in other countries and thus affects them adversely. The argument is logically well founded. It is important, however, to understand its scope and its limits.
To do so, it is useful to start with a discussion of the issue in normal times, that is, when interest rates are positive throughout the world. In that case, the argument just does not carry: Countries can run surpluses or deficits without necessarily affecting output in other countries, because interest rates and exchange rates can be adjusted to maintain output at potential in all countries.
Indeed, if central banks target stable inflation, the adjustment of interest rates and the implied exchange rate adjustments will take place naturally.
Suppose that a country wants to increase its saving rate. To counteract the decrease in domestic demand and avoid a decline in output, the central bank will reduce the interest rate, leading to exchange rate depreciation and an improvement in the current account. Faced with an exchange rate appreciation and thus a deterioration of their current account, central banks in the rest of the world will then decrease interest rates so as to maintain their output at potential. The global outcome will be a decrease in interest rates across the world, an exchange rate depreciation and a larger current account surplus of the original country vis-àvis the rest of the world. Output will remain at potential, both in the
original country and in the rest of the world. (The appendix provides a simple formalization of this argument and of the arguments below.)
One may argue, however, that the end result is still a larger current account deficit in the rest of the world and that, as we have seen earlier, large current account deficits can prove dangerous. The argument only goes so far: first, even a large surplus in a large country can be offset by small current account deficits across all countries in the rest of the world. Second, and more important empirically, major deficit countries have surely not been “forced” to make the policy and behavioral choices that have resulted in large deficits. Had they not made those choices, both current account surpluses and deficits would have been smaller.
Along related lines, one might also argue that if large desired current account surpluses in many countries lead to low interest rates in other countries, this may in turn encourage risk taking and lead to financial excesses in those countries. This mechanism plays an important role in some interpretations of the recent financial crisis that see global imbalances as a key causal factor: large surpluses led to low interest rates, which in turn led to excessive risk taking. This argument again only goes so far: prudential measures in deficit countries would have been and are the appropriate policy response to domestic financial excesses, rather than reductions in current account balances in surplus countries.
The argument on the negative multilateral repercussions of large desired current account surpluses becomes stronger, however, when interest rates cannot decrease in the rest of the world. When countries are in a liquidity trap, as is arguably the case today in several large advanced economies, the interest rate cannot decrease if desired global saving rises. In this case, large current account surpluses in some countries can lead to low aggregate demand and lower output in other countries. In principle, these countries could use fiscal policy to sustain domestic demand; but in current circumstances the room for expansionary fiscal policy is severely curtailed by debt sustainability concerns. Thus a decrease in current account surpluses in surplus countries, through a combination of real exchange rate appreciation and higher domestic demand, can lead to higher output in current account deficit countries.
Given current circumstances, we see this as a convincing argument for multilateral guidelines on current account surplus countries. But it should be clear that the argument is time and country specific. It would lose relevance in a world in which the equilibrium interest rate for advanced economies (those for which liquidity-trap considerations are currently relevant) became positive, the case we expect to prevail in the not too distant future.
IV. Implications for “Rules of the Game”
The arguments sketched in the previous sections suggest that there are both domestic and multilateral reasons for countries to reduce current account deficits and surpluses under certain circumstances.
We have argued that, in many cases, current account balances reflect underlying domestic distortions. It is then in the interest of the country to remove those distortions and, in the process, reducing imbalances. This part is clear. The more difficult issue is why this should be the subject of multilateral discussions or surveillance. We can think of a few arguments. Domestic obstacles to the adoption of these policies come from several angles, from differences in the assessment of costs and benefits (particularly if the adjustment process can entail short-term costs and long-term benefits) to political economy considerations. One may then think of a multilateral surveillance process as playing two potentially useful roles: first, as a useful discussion of the differences in assessments; second, and perhaps more relevant, as a po- tentially useful commitment device for countries to implement some of the required but politically unpalatable fiscal or structural adjustments(this last argument is clearly one of the main motivations behind the proposals for multilateral rules for fiscal policy within the euro area and the European Union).
We have then examined the case where spillover effects, either from deficits or surpluses, suggest a direct role for multilateral surveillance. We have argued that:
Worries about cross-border effects of sudden stops justify multilateral surveillance. They also suggest, however, looking beyond the current account deficit, at the whole structure of the capital account.
Worries about unfair competitive advantage may justify restrictions on undervaluation and current account surpluses, but implementation is likely to be difficult. Proving intent may be next to impossible. Ignoring intent may be unfair.
Worries about global demand if part of the world economy is in a liquidity trap. In that context, smaller current account surpluses in surplus countries might actually benefit growth in the rest of the world. The relevant question is why surplus countries should oblige. One answer is based on a repeated-game argument: a surplus country today may be a deficit country in the future, and thus benefit from such a rule. The argument is not convincing: the world economy is not ergodic, and the likelihood that the roles will be reversed in the future is small. Another, more pragmatic, argument is that in many (but not all) surplus countries domestic and multilateral considerations actually go in the same direction. To the extent that these countries reduce domestic distortions, this will be good for them, and good for the rest of the world. And, even if one could hope for more, this can go a long way toward strengthening the world recovery.